
This article needs additional citations for verification.(May 2015) |
Common goods (also called common-pool resources) are defined in economics as goods that are rivalrous and non-excludable. Thus, they constitute one of the four main types based on the criteria:
- whether the consumption of a good by one person precludes its consumption by another person (rivalrousness)
- whether it is possible to prevent people (consumers) who have not paid for it from having access to it (excludability)

As common goods are accessible by everybody, they are at risk of being subject to overexploitation which leads to diminished availability if people act to serve their own self-interests.
History
Despite its growing importance in modern society, the concept of the common good was first mentioned more than two thousand years ago in the writings of Plato, Aristotle, and Cicero. Regardless the time period Aristotle described the problem with common goods accurately: “What is common to many is taken least care of, for all men have greater regard for what is their own than for what they possess in common with others.”
Examples
Congested roads - Roads may be considered either public or common resources. Road is public good whenever there is no congestion, thus the use of the road does not affect the use of someone else. However, if the road is congested, one more person driving the car makes the road more crowded which causes slower passage. In other words, it creates a negative externality and road becomes common good.
Clean water and air - Climate stability belongs to classic modern examples. Water and air pollution is caused by market negative externality. Water flows can be tapped beyond sustainability, and air is often used in combustion, whether by motor vehicles, smokers, factories, wood fires. In the production process these resources and others are changed into finished products such as food, shoes, toys, furniture, cars, houses and televisions.
Fish stocks in international waters - Oceans remain one of the least regulated common resources. When fish are withdrawn from the water without any limits being imposed just because of their commercial value, living stocks of fish are likely to be depleted for any later fishermen. This phenomenon is caused by no incentives to let fish for others. To describe situations in which economic users withdraw resources to secure short-term gains without regard for the long-term consequences, the term tragedy of the commons was coined. For example, forest exploitation leads to barren lands, and overfishing leads to a reduction of overall fish stocks, both of which eventually result in diminishing yields to be withdrawn periodically.
Other natural resources - Another example of a private exploitation treated as a renewable resource and commonly cited have been trees or timber at critical stages, oil, mined metals, crops, or freely accessible grazing.
Debates about sustainability can be both philosophical and scientific. However, wise-use advocates consider common goods that are an exploitable form of a renewable resource, such as fish stocks, grazing land, etc., to be sustainable in the following two cases:
- As long as demand for the goods withdrawn from the common good does not exceed a certain level, future yields are not diminished and the common good as such is being preserved as a 'sustainable' level.
- If access to the common good is regulated at the community level by restricting exploitation to community members and by imposing limits to the quantity of goods being withdrawn from the common good, the tragedy of the commons may be avoided. Common goods that are sustained through an institutional arrangement of this kind are referred to as common-pool resources.
Tragedy of the commons
Tragedy of commons is a problem in economics in which everybody has an incentive to use a resource at the expense of everyone else who uses it, with no way of preventing anyone from consuming it. Generally, the resource in question is without barriers to entry and is demanded in excess of its supply, leading to depletion of the resource.
The tragedy of the commons was originally mentioned in 1833 by the Victorian economist William Forster Lloyd, who was a member of the Royal Society. He offered the example of a hypothetical tract of shared grazing land, in which all of the villagers brought their cows to this common grazing space, resulting in overgrazing and the depletion of the resource (Lloyd, 1833). Individuals may theoretically limit their use in order to avoid depleting a shared resource, if they so chose. However, there is a problem with free riders. In situations where people rely on others to reduce their productivity. The result of everyone taking advantage of the system and making the most of it is a scenario of over-consumption.
Example
For example, imagine there are several shepherds, each with their own flock of sheep, who have access to a communal field which they all use for grazing. As the sheep graze unhindered, they deplete the overall stock of grass in the field and there is less for other sheep to consume. The tragedy is that eventually the field will become barren and will be no use to any of the shepherds.
Possible solutions include:
- Assigning property rights. This involves essentially converting what was a common-pool resource into a private good. This would prevent that over-consumption of the good as the owner(s) of the good would have an incentive to regulate their consumption in order to keep the stock of that good at a healthy level.
- Government intervention. Right to use the land can be allocated, the number of sheep in every herd can be regulated or externality made by sheep can be internalized by taxing sheep.
- Collective solutions can also be reached to solve the problem. Before English enclosure laws were enacted, there were agreements in place between lords and rural villagers to overcome this problem. Practices such as seasonal grazing and crop rotation regulated land use. Over-using the land resulted in enforceable sanctions.
Common goods and normal goods
Normal goods are goods that experience an increase in demand as the income of consumers increases. The demand function of a normal good is downward sloping, which means there is an inverse relationship between the price and quantity demanded. In other words, price elasticity of demand is negative for normal goods. Common goods mean that demand and price change in the opposite direction. If something is a normal good, then the consumer's demand for the goods and the consumer's income level change in the same direction. At this time, the substitution effect and income effect will strengthen each other, so the price change will lead to the opposite direction of demand change. Then the goods must be common goods, so the normal goods must be a common goods.
Other goods
Excludable | Non-excludable | |
---|---|---|
Rivalrous | Private goods eg. food, clothing, parking spaces | Common-pool resources eg. fish stocks, timber |
Non-rivalrous | Club goods eg. cinemas, software, private parks | Public goods eg. free-to-air television, air, national defense |
In addition to common goods, there are three other kinds of economic goods, including public goods, private goods, and club goods. Common goods that a businessman gives a thumbs up can include international fish stocks and other goods. Most international fishing areas have no limit on the number of fish that can be caught. Therefore, anyone can fish as he likes, which makes the good things not excluded. However, if there are no restrictions, fish stocks may be depleted when other fishermen arrive later. This means that fish populations are competitive. Other common commodities include water and game animals.
See also
- Common-pool resource
- Social goods
- Social trap
- Somebody else's problem
- Stone Soup – a story opposite the tragedy of the commons
- Tragedy of the anticommons
- Tyranny of small decisions
- Tragedy of the commons
- Game theory
- Public good
References
Citations
- Mankiw, N.Gregory (2015). Principles of Economics (7th ed.). Cengage Learning, Inc. pp. 215–229. ISBN 978-1-285-16587-5.
- "Dimitrova, A., Hollan, K., Laster, D., Reinstaller, A., Schratzenstaller, M., Walterskirchen, E., Weiss, T. 2013 (September). Literature review on fundamental concepts and definitions, objectives and policy goals as well as instruments relevant for socio-ecological transition Working, Paper no 40, accessed May 14, 2015" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on March 6, 2016. Retrieved May 15, 2015.
- Isik, J. 2011 (5 December ). Sustainability: A Number of Policy Points Focusing on the Environment and Global Warming, Social Europe, accessed May 14, 2015 Archived April 14, 2015, at the Wayback Machine
- Rawsthornjan, A. Debating Sustainability, January 31, 2010
- "OConnor, N. From Conspicuous Consumption to Collective Consumption, 1 December 2011". Archived from the original on 18 May 2015. Retrieved 15 May 2015.
- Hardin, Garrett (1968-12-13). "The Tragedy of the Commons". Science. 162 (3859). American Association for the Advancement of Science: 1243–1248. Bibcode:1968Sci...162.1243H. doi:10.1126/science.162.3859.1243. eISSN 1095-9203. ISSN 0036-8075. PMID 5699198.
- Investopedia Staff. "Tragedy Of The Commons Definition". Investopedia. Archived from the original on 2010-03-27. Retrieved 2021-04-30.
- "What are Normal Goods?". Corporate Finance Institute. Retrieved 26 April 2022.
Bibliography
- "Two lectures on the checks of population, delivered before the University of Oxford, in Michaelmas term 1832., by W. F. Lloyd | The Online Books Page". onlinebooks.library.upenn.edu. Retrieved 2022-05-09.
- Jenkins, Megan E.; Simmons, Randy; Lofthouse, Jordan; Edwards, Eric (2022-05-09). "The Environmental Optimism of Elinor Ostrom". The Center for Growth and Opportunity.
- Hardin, Garrett (1968-12-13). "The Tragedy of the Commons". Science. 162 (3859). American Association for the Advancement of Science: 1243–1248. Bibcode:1968Sci...162.1243H. doi:10.1126/science.162.3859.1243. ISSN 0036-8075. PMID 5699198.
- Mankiw, N.Gregory (2015). Principles of Economics (7th ed.). USA: Cengage Learning, Inc. ISBN 978-1-285-16587-5.
- Ostrom, Elinor; Roy, Gardner; Walker, James (1994). Rules, games, and common-pool resources. United States of America: University of Michigan Press. ISBN 0-472-09546-3.
- Tirole, Jean (2017). Economics for the Common Good. USA, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-17516-4.
This article needs additional citations for verification Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed Find sources Common good economics news newspapers books scholar JSTOR May 2015 Learn how and when to remove this message Common goods also called common pool resources are defined in economics as goods that are rivalrous and non excludable Thus they constitute one of the four main types based on the criteria whether the consumption of a good by one person precludes its consumption by another person rivalrousness whether it is possible to prevent people consumers who have not paid for it from having access to it excludability Wild fish are an example of common goods They are non excludable as it is impossible to prevent people from catching fish They are however rivalrous as the same fish cannot be caught more than once As common goods are accessible by everybody they are at risk of being subject to overexploitation which leads to diminished availability if people act to serve their own self interests HistoryDespite its growing importance in modern society the concept of the common good was first mentioned more than two thousand years ago in the writings of Plato Aristotle and Cicero Regardless the time period Aristotle described the problem with common goods accurately What is common to many is taken least care of for all men have greater regard for what is their own than for what they possess in common with others ExamplesCongested roads Roads may be considered either public or common resources Road is public good whenever there is no congestion thus the use of the road does not affect the use of someone else However if the road is congested one more person driving the car makes the road more crowded which causes slower passage In other words it creates a negative externality and road becomes common good Clean water and air Climate stability belongs to classic modern examples Water and air pollution is caused by market negative externality Water flows can be tapped beyond sustainability and air is often used in combustion whether by motor vehicles smokers factories wood fires In the production process these resources and others are changed into finished products such as food shoes toys furniture cars houses and televisions Fish stocks in international waters Oceans remain one of the least regulated common resources When fish are withdrawn from the water without any limits being imposed just because of their commercial value living stocks of fish are likely to be depleted for any later fishermen This phenomenon is caused by no incentives to let fish for others To describe situations in which economic users withdraw resources to secure short term gains without regard for the long term consequences the term tragedy of the commons was coined For example forest exploitation leads to barren lands and overfishing leads to a reduction of overall fish stocks both of which eventually result in diminishing yields to be withdrawn periodically Other natural resources Another example of a private exploitation treated as a renewable resource and commonly cited have been trees or timber at critical stages oil mined metals crops or freely accessible grazing Debates about sustainability can be both philosophical and scientific However wise use advocates consider common goods that are an exploitable form of a renewable resource such as fish stocks grazing land etc to be sustainable in the following two cases As long as demand for the goods withdrawn from the common good does not exceed a certain level future yields are not diminished and the common good as such is being preserved as a sustainable level If access to the common good is regulated at the community level by restricting exploitation to community members and by imposing limits to the quantity of goods being withdrawn from the common good the tragedy of the commons may be avoided Common goods that are sustained through an institutional arrangement of this kind are referred to as common pool resources Tragedy of the commonsTragedy of commons is a problem in economics in which everybody has an incentive to use a resource at the expense of everyone else who uses it with no way of preventing anyone from consuming it Generally the resource in question is without barriers to entry and is demanded in excess of its supply leading to depletion of the resource The tragedy of the commons was originally mentioned in 1833 by the Victorian economist William Forster Lloyd who was a member of the Royal Society He offered the example of a hypothetical tract of shared grazing land in which all of the villagers brought their cows to this common grazing space resulting in overgrazing and the depletion of the resource Lloyd 1833 Individuals may theoretically limit their use in order to avoid depleting a shared resource if they so chose However there is a problem with free riders In situations where people rely on others to reduce their productivity The result of everyone taking advantage of the system and making the most of it is a scenario of over consumption Example For example imagine there are several shepherds each with their own flock of sheep who have access to a communal field which they all use for grazing As the sheep graze unhindered they deplete the overall stock of grass in the field and there is less for other sheep to consume The tragedy is that eventually the field will become barren and will be no use to any of the shepherds Possible solutions include Assigning property rights This involves essentially converting what was a common pool resource into a private good This would prevent that over consumption of the good as the owner s of the good would have an incentive to regulate their consumption in order to keep the stock of that good at a healthy level Government intervention Right to use the land can be allocated the number of sheep in every herd can be regulated or externality made by sheep can be internalized by taxing sheep Collective solutions can also be reached to solve the problem Before English enclosure laws were enacted there were agreements in place between lords and rural villagers to overcome this problem Practices such as seasonal grazing and crop rotation regulated land use Over using the land resulted in enforceable sanctions Common goods and normal goodsNormal goods are goods that experience an increase in demand as the income of consumers increases The demand function of a normal good is downward sloping which means there is an inverse relationship between the price and quantity demanded In other words price elasticity of demand is negative for normal goods Common goods mean that demand and price change in the opposite direction If something is a normal good then the consumer s demand for the goods and the consumer s income level change in the same direction At this time the substitution effect and income effect will strengthen each other so the price change will lead to the opposite direction of demand change Then the goods must be common goods so the normal goods must be a common goods Other goodsExcludable Non excludableRivalrous Private goods eg food clothing parking spaces Common pool resources eg fish stocks timberNon rivalrous Club goods eg cinemas software private parks Public goods eg free to air television air national defense In addition to common goods there are three other kinds of economic goods including public goods private goods and club goods Common goods that a businessman gives a thumbs up can include international fish stocks and other goods Most international fishing areas have no limit on the number of fish that can be caught Therefore anyone can fish as he likes which makes the good things not excluded However if there are no restrictions fish stocks may be depleted when other fishermen arrive later This means that fish populations are competitive Other common commodities include water and game animals See alsoCommon pool resource Social goods Social trap Somebody else s problem Stone Soup a story opposite the tragedy of the commons Tragedy of the anticommons Tyranny of small decisions Tragedy of the commons Game theory Public goodReferencesCitations Mankiw N Gregory 2015 Principles of Economics 7th ed Cengage Learning Inc pp 215 229 ISBN 978 1 285 16587 5 Dimitrova A Hollan K Laster D Reinstaller A Schratzenstaller M Walterskirchen E Weiss T 2013 September Literature review on fundamental concepts and definitions objectives and policy goals as well as instruments relevant for socio ecological transition Working Paper no 40 accessed May 14 2015 PDF Archived from the original PDF on March 6 2016 Retrieved May 15 2015 Isik J 2011 5 December Sustainability A Number of Policy Points Focusing on the Environment and Global Warming Social Europe accessed May 14 2015 Archived April 14 2015 at the Wayback Machine Rawsthornjan A Debating Sustainability January 31 2010 OConnor N From Conspicuous Consumption to Collective Consumption 1 December 2011 Archived from the original on 18 May 2015 Retrieved 15 May 2015 Hardin Garrett 1968 12 13 The Tragedy of the Commons Science 162 3859 American Association for the Advancement of Science 1243 1248 Bibcode 1968Sci 162 1243H doi 10 1126 science 162 3859 1243 eISSN 1095 9203 ISSN 0036 8075 PMID 5699198 Investopedia Staff Tragedy Of The Commons Definition Investopedia Archived from the original on 2010 03 27 Retrieved 2021 04 30 What are Normal Goods Corporate Finance Institute Retrieved 26 April 2022 Bibliography Two lectures on the checks of population delivered before the University of Oxford in Michaelmas term 1832 by W F Lloyd The Online Books Page onlinebooks library upenn edu Retrieved 2022 05 09 Jenkins Megan E Simmons Randy Lofthouse Jordan Edwards Eric 2022 05 09 The Environmental Optimism of Elinor Ostrom The Center for Growth and Opportunity Hardin Garrett 1968 12 13 The Tragedy of the Commons Science 162 3859 American Association for the Advancement of Science 1243 1248 Bibcode 1968Sci 162 1243H doi 10 1126 science 162 3859 1243 ISSN 0036 8075 PMID 5699198 Mankiw N Gregory 2015 Principles of Economics 7th ed USA Cengage Learning Inc ISBN 978 1 285 16587 5 Ostrom Elinor Roy Gardner Walker James 1994 Rules games and common pool resources United States of America University of Michigan Press ISBN 0 472 09546 3 Tirole Jean 2017 Economics for the Common Good USA New Jersey Princeton University Press ISBN 978 0 691 17516 4